Like a bad recurring dream, we in the US are once again talking about the “debt ceiling”.

The discussion about public debt is often buttressed by two misconceptions about the economy I would like to dispel.

The first has to do with the government being constrained like a family by its budget and having to spend no more than it brings in.

The second has to do with government debt and how important it is to reduce it.

Both concepts reveal a complete ignorance of basic macroeconomics and make possible the abomination of “austerity” – a brutal and counterproductive economic policy.

Unlike microeconomics, which focuses on individual economic agents (individuals and businesses), macroeconomics deals with the economy as an aggregate. It requires a different way of thinking.

The key concept of macroeconomics is GDP (gross domestic product) which is a measure of the economic output of a country.

I am no fan of GDP as a measure of collective well-being and of the need for it to grow at all costs. I share the sentiments expressed by the then US-Presidential candidate Robert Kennedy during his speech at the University of Kansas on March 18, 1968.

Nevertheless, we need to understand GDP and its components in order to dispel the two misconceptions above.

The GDP can be expressed either in terms of expenditures or incomes.

The expenditure expression of GPD is the following

GDP = private consumption + gross business investment + government spending + (exports – imports)

or for short

GDP = C + I + G + (X – M)

We can also express GDP in terms of income. Here is a very stylized way of doing so.

GDP = wage for labor + interest for capital + rent for land + profits for entrepreneurship

Here is the key concept to understand. You as an individual or any economic entity like a family or a business, have a luxury a nation as a whole does not have – the independence between income and expenditures. You can decide to spend less than you earn and save some of your income for the future. Or you might borrow and spend now beyond your current income.

The fact that GDP can be expressed either in terms of expenditures or in terms of incomes makes clear that, as soon as you expand your scope of analysis to the economy of an entire nation, there is no independence between income and expenditures – the total national income is equal to (is generated by) the total amount of expenditures in the economy! Every dollar of income in the economy comes from a dollar somebody else spent.  From a macroeconomic standpoint, if you reduce expenditures (either because consumer spending is down, or business investments are down, or government spending is down or imports grow faster than exports) you will also reduce national income.

Hence, it becomes clear the role of government spending in counteracting the effects of an economic downturn, as we have seen in a very dramatic way recently during the early stage of the COVID-19 pandemic. While an argument could be made that the size of that fiscal stimulus was in part responsible for the recent bout of inflation, there is no doubt that in the absence of such stimulus the economic consequences could have been catastrophic.

During an economic recession, consumers spend less and businesses invest less given the soft demand in the economy. The only way for the national income to remain at the same level is for the government to pick up the slack and increase its spending into the economy, sometimes with direct cash transfers as it has happened in the last few years. To demand that a government  balance its budget during an economic recession, while both consumers and business curtail their spending, or even worse to force it to reduce its debt like Greece in the last decade, is to exacerbate the contraction of the economy and therefore to further reduce the national income.

During economic recessions governments are therefore likely to increase their indebtedness. The recession causes both a reduction in the tax receipts due to the slowdown in the personal and corporate income while at the same time government expenditures in terms of unemployment benefits and other programs to alleviate hunger and poverty go up. Raising taxes would exacerbate the problem, so it is typical, and in fact advisable, for a government to increase its borrowing during an economic recession to support the aggregate national income.

But isn’t government debt something bad and ideally something that needs to be reduced and eventually eliminated?

The answer is no, if a government is monetarily sovereign. Let me explain.

A government that issues its debt in its own currency and has a central bank in a position to acquire its debt, will never be insolvent.

The central bank can buy government securities by simply expanding its balance sheet and there is no limit imposed on its size. The central bank actually creates the money it needs whenever it buys financial assets.

Debt doomsayers warn of skyrocketing interest rates on the national debt as it grows without realizing that the interest on the national debt is a policy lever that can be influenced by the Fed’s purchases.

Case in point, for a number of years starting during the Second World War, the Fed was tasked with engaging in open market operations (buying and selling government bonds) to keep the interest rates on government debt to 0.375%. The policy was abandoned in the early 50s to allow the Federal Reserve better flexibility in managing inflation. Moreover, from 2008 until early 2022 the Federal Reserve engaged in the so called Quantitative Easing – a massive purchasing of government debt with the goal of reducing long term interest rates showing one more time that the interest on the national debt is not exclusively controlled by free market forces but can be set as a policy variable by the Fed.

You might remember that a few years ago there was an ominous debt clock a block away from Times Square in NYC inexorably marching towards the level of $10,000,000,000,000. Debt doomsayers were warning about disastrous consequences and skyrocketing interest rates if that magic threshold was breached. Well since then the original debt watch ran out of digits and a new one was built a few blocks away, the national debt now stands at close to $31 trillion ($31,000,000,000,000).  Note that during the time the national debt went from $10T (Q4 2008)  to $30T (Q1 2022) we have experienced the period with the lowest  interest rates in modern history until the Federal Reserve decided to increase them to deal with the recent bout of inflation. Hence, the interest rates have not been increased as a consequence of the growing amount of government debt but by virtue of a policy decision make by the Federal Reserve.

What is crucial to understand is that the aggregate government debt expresses the desire of the private sector for savings. In other words, our national debt can be seen as our national savings. Let me explain.

We said before that GDP can be expressed as follows GDP = C + I + G + (X – M)

GDP is also equal to the national income and you can divide it into the portion of the income that is consumed, saved and taxed. So GDP = C + S + T

With grade school algebra you can rearrange the terms and get to this relationship which is called the sectoral balances equation.

(S – I) = (G – T) + (X-M)

Net saving at a national level (savings minus investments) is equal to net government spending (government spending minus taxes) plus net exports (exports minus imports). The nice thing about an accounting identity is that it has to be true and, unsurprisingly, the actual data confirms it.

US sectoral balances

There were only two periods in our recent economic history when the private sector had negative net savings and both times it ended badly – the first time was during the technology bubble of the late 90s and more recently during the buildup in the real estate bubble leading to the financial crisis of 2007-2008.

Most of the time the private sector is interested in accumulating net saving positions and that is primarily made possible by government net spending, in other words, by an increase in the national debt. It is also helpful to remember that the vast majority of the US national debt is held in the savings of other US individuals, businesses or other government entities.

The key insight regarding the relationship between national debt and private savings becomes crystal clear in the case of a closed economy, one without any trading with other nations (in other words with no imports and no exports).

In the case of a closed economy the sectoral balances equations becomes

Net private savings = net government spending

This shows that the level of government debt expresses the desire of the private sector for net savings.

So how can we have a mature and informed conversation about the national debt?

It helps to start from the understanding, hopefully gained by what you read above, that the US, being monetarily sovereign,  will never be forced to default on its debt by markets or international investors. If it defaults on its debt it will be a self-inflicted wound caused by irresponsible actions by Congress using a technicality to refuse to pay for the expenditures and commitments  Congress already agreed upon.

Often the discussion on raising the debt ceiling is couched in terms of raising the borrowing limit on a credit card. It would be more accurate to describe it as deciding whether to pay for the next car loan payment after one has already bought a car on credit. It should be noted that the 14th amendment on the US Constitution states that “The validity of the public debt of the United States, authorized by law, including debts incurred for payment of pensions and bounties for services in suppressing insurrection or rebellion, shall not be questioned”. Those in Congress who are threatening a possible default of the US government debt by refusing to raise the debt ceiling are therefore acting contrary to the US Constitution they swore to uphold when they took office.

Having said that, we should have a mature conversation about the growing US public debt mostly because of the crowding effect on the US budget exerted by the increasing debt servicing cost. In light of the fact that the aggregate government debt expresses the desire of the private sector for savings, to reduce the national debt we would need to consider policies aimed at reducing the private sector desire for savings rather than investing, a topic for another blog.

Author: Marco Vangelisti

Marco Vangelisti, Chartered Financial Analyst (CFA) is a 100% Aware™ and No-Harm™ Investor with a longstanding commitment to Positive and Restorative Investing™.

6 Replies to “Let’s talk about debt and the economy”

  1. Really appreciate the discussion and visualization with graphs.
    One thing as I understand it the GDP is a monitoring tool – however it is put together- so it is a simplistic representation that the “accountants of the economy” put together. There are other monitoring tools that I look for to be used in conjunction with the GDP, such as a measure of the quality of life – perhaps a Gross Happiness Product. Clearly though, the economic macro decision framework does matter – and its good to lift the hood on the policys.
    I realize its complicated, but I would be interested in a discussion also of economies where there has been a lot of unhappiness and despair – possibly caused by an IMF fashion – such as Argentina, Zimbabwe, Venezula, Russia, Thailand. There are modern economies that possibly avoided IMF text book fashions such as China, India and Brazil with possibly more sucess . There are also the modern real-life and the changing nature of “sovereign money” as in Greece/Italy/Spain/Ireland with the EU.
    Many thanks again for the article.

  2. The other way to interpret the sector balances equation in a closed economy that is stated as net government spending (the debt minus taxes) equals net private savings (savings minus investment) – IS that higher government debt results in Lower private investment (which was netted out of savings). Not a good thing. Yes the government can soften the effects of a recession by increasing government spending. BUT we are 7-8 years out now from the Great Recession and government deficits are still high. Not a good equation for younger generations – our kids and grandkids – who will be the ones to deal with our excessive debt run-up.

    1. Hi Sharon,

      thanks for the thoughtful comment. The causation is more likely reversed from what you suggest. It is in periods of weak economic conditions that businesses retrench from investing and the demand for government services increase at the same time as its tax receipts soften. Greater government debt therefore tends to be the result of business underinvestment as opposed to the cause. Clearly, one way to eliminate government debt is to tax all the private savings in the economy and retire public debt – probably not what you would argue for. Keep in mind that some of government spending could be classified as investments, e.g. rebuilding our infrastructure. So an argument could be made that when the private sector is insufficiently motivated by profit to invest, an entity like the government might be called upon to do investments motivated by the public good rather than profit. This is probably a larger discussion having to do with how much we can actually trust the government to operate in the common interest…

      1. I have long felt that private ‘for profit’ interests have failed to pay their fair share of the costs for health care, education, safety, highways, waste disposal, etc. To rectify this would require a new way of thinking. Consumer products involve more than just the manufacture of goods from raw materials. Once a ‘product’ is conceived, putting the raw materials together requires transport and educating the public in it’s use. The educating part is sometimes called advertising (only a small part of educating though – cigarettes are an example), however, transporting the raw materials requires heavy use of highways and rails and air, all which consume public funds to make the means available. Likewise, once the product reaches it’s useful life the resulting ‘waste’ must be dealt with, even if it is a private concern, they are using landfill, public air (burning), or some other means which eventually will require some form of public dealing. Eventually, we will all face a water shortage due to population extending beyond limits which the natural world will impose. Regulations and some kind of public input will have to be imposed to insure that not just the wealthy have access to water! I know this is just a short note dealing with a huge topic but in the end, there are NO market forces to deal with these issues! Living within our means requires more than just an ‘economic’ viewpoint! Climate change is going to force the issue and perhaps humans are not up to the challenge!

    2. “net government spending (the debt minus taxes) equals net private savings (savings minus investment) – IS that higher government debt results in Lower private investment (which was netted out of savings).”

      “Government debt” is, in my opinion, a misnomer. What we call government debt is simply the total amount of outstanding US treasury bills. These bonds are held by investors in the US (and to a lesser extent abroad, but that is of little consequence, they are dollar denominated), as well as pension funds, both public and private. The largest share of US treasuries is held by the government itself, primarily the Social Security and Medicare trust funds.

      Net government spending is the difference between total government spending and taxes. If that number is negative in a given year there is a public deficit for that year. As the sectoral balances analysis illustrates, the private sector will then be in surplus for that year. That is a desirable consequence. Thus government deficit spending is a positive policy, not just in times of recession but nearly always.

  3. Thanks for the interesting economics lesson. While i agree with the main points, and that government indebtedness is over-emphasized as a political point, I would be interested in how you factor in the moral impact of inattention to budgetary balance, and escalating debt ceilings. The U.S. economic recovery began a long time ago, and has lasted, so it would be positive if the trend in federal debt wasn’t ignored.
    In the latest housing bust, many people who could afford mortgage payments because they remained employed nevertheless opted to not make payments if the value to lien ratio was below 1.0. College graduates were demanding student loan forgiveness, and occupied New York’s Zucotti Park. Combine those with corporations who file for bankruptcy for strategic, not purely financial reasons (about which one famous politician recently bragged), and you can imagine that while Polonius’ advice to Laertes about borrowing may have been extreme, the other end of the spectrum is no place to be either.

Leave a Reply

%d